James P. Scanlan, Attorney at Law

Home Page

Curriculum Vitae

Publications

Published Articles

Conference Presentations

Working Papers

page1

Journal Comments

Truth in Justice Articles

Measurement Letters

Measuring Health Disp

Outline and Guide to MHD

Summary to MHD

Solutions

page3

Solutions Database

Irreducible Minimums

Pay for Performance

Between Group Variance

Concentration Index

Gini Coefficient

Reporting Heterogeneity

Cohort Considerations

Relative v Absolute Diff

Whitehall Studies

AHRQ's Vanderbilt Report

NHDR Measurement

NHDR Technical Issues

MHD A Articles

MHD B Conf Presentations

MHD D Journal Comments

Consensus/Non-Consensus

Spurious Contradictions

Institutional Corresp

page2

Scanlan's Rule

Outline and Guide to SR

Summary to SR

Bibliography

Semantic Issues

Employment Tests

Case Study

Case Study Answers

Case Study II

Subgroup Effects

Subgroup Effects NC

Illogical Premises

Illogical Premises II

Inevitable Interaction

Interactions by Age

Literacy Illustration

RERI

Feminization of Poverty S

Explanatory Theories

Mortality and Survival

Truncation Issues

Collected Illustrations

Income Illustrations

Framingham Illustrations

Life Table Illustrations

NHANES Illustrations

Mort/Surv Illustration

Credit Score Illustration

Intermediate Outcomes

Representational Disp

Statistical Signif SR

Comparing Averages

Meta-Analysis

Case Control Studies

Criminal Record Effects

Sears Case Illustration

Numeracy Illustration

Obesity Illusration

LIHTC Approval Disparitie

Recidivism Illustration

Consensus

Algorithm Fairness

Mortality and Survival 2

Mort/Survival Update

Measures of Association

Immunization Disparities

Race Health Initiative

Educational Disparities

Disparities by Subject

CUNY ISLG Eq Indicators

Harvard CRP NCLB Study

New York Proficiency Disp

Education Trust GC Study

Education Trust HA Study

AE Casey Profic Study

McKinsey Achiev Gap Study

California RICA

Nuclear Deterrence

Employment Discrimination

Job Segregation

Measuring Hiring Discr

Disparate Impact

Four-Fifths Rule

Less Discr Alt - Proc

Less Discr Altl - Subs

Fisher v. Transco Serv

Jones v. City of Boston

Bottom Line Issue

Lending Disparities

Inc & Cred Score Example

Disparities - High Income

Underadjustment Issues

Absolute Differences - L

Lathern v. NationsBank

US v. Countrywide

US v. Wells Fargo

Partial Picture Issues

Foreclosure Disparities

File Comparison Issues

FHA/VA Steering Study

CAP TARP Study

Disparities by Sector

Holder/Perez Letter

Federal Reserve Letter

Discipline Disparities

COPAA v. DeVos

Kerri K. V. California

Truancy Illustration

Disparate Treatment

Relative Absolute Diff

Offense Type Issues

Los Angeles SWPBS

Oakland Disparities

Richmond Disparities

Nashville Disparities

California Disparities

Denver Disparities

Colorado Disparities

Nor Carolina Disparitie

Aurora Disparities

Allegheny County Disp

Evansville Disparities

Maryland Disparities

St. Paul Disparities

Seattle Disparities

Minneapolis Disparities

Oregon Disparities

Beaverton Disparities

Montgomery County Disp

Henrico County Disparitie

Florida Disparities

Connecticut Disparities

Portland Disparities

Minnesota Disparities

Massachusetts Disparities

Rhode Island Disparities

South Bend Disparities

Utah Disparities

Loudoun Cty Disparities

Kern County Disparities

Milwaukee Disparities

Urbana Disparities

Illinois Disparities

Virginia Disparities

Behavior

Suburban Disparities

Preschool Disparities

Restraint Disparities

Disabilities - PL 108-446

Keep Kids in School Act

Gender Disparities

Ferguson Arrest Disp

NEPC Colorado Study

NEPC National Study

California Prison Pop

APA Zero Tolerance Study

Flawed Inferences - Disc

Oakland Agreement

DOE Equity Report

IDEA Data Center Guide

Duncan/Ali Letter

Crim Justice Disparities

U.S. Customs Search Disp

Deescalation Training

Career Criminal Study

Implicit Bias Training

Drawing Inferences

Diversion Programs

Minneapolis PD Investig

Offense Type Issues CJD

Innumerate Decree Monitor

Massachusetts CJ Disparit

Feminization of Poverty

Affirmative Action

Affirm Action for Women

Other Affirm Action

Justice John Paul Stevens

Statistical Reasoning

The Sears Case

Sears Case Documents

The AT&T Consent Decree

Cross v. ASPI

Vignettes

Times Higher Issues

Gender Diff in DADT Term

Adjustment Issues

Percentage Points

Odds Ratios

Statistical Signif Vig

Journalists & Statistics

Multiplication Definition

Prosecutorial Misconduct

Outline and Guide

Misconduct Summary

B1 Agent Cain Testimony

B1a Bev Wilsh Diversion

B2 Bk Entry re Cain Call

B3 John Mitchell Count

B3a Obscuring Msg Slips

B3b Missing Barksdale Int

B4 Park Towers

B5 Dean 1997 Motion

B6 Demery Testimony

B7 Sankin Receipts

B7a Sankin HBS App

B8 DOJ Complicity

B9 Doc Manager Complaints

B9a Fabricated Gov Exh 25

B11a DC Bar Complaint

Letters (Misconduct)

Links Page

Misconduct Profiles

Arlin M. Adams

Jo Ann Harris

Bruce C. Swartz

Swartz Addendum 2

Swartz Addendum 3

Swartz Addendum 4

Swartz Addendum 7

Robert E. O'Neill

O'Neill Addendum 7

Paula A. Sweeney

Robert J. Meyer

Lantos Hearings

Password Protected

OIC Doc Manager Material

DC Bar Materials

Temp Confidential

DV Issues

Indexes

Document Storage

Pre 1989

1989 - present

Presentations

Prosec Misc Docs

Prosec Misc Docs II

Profile PDFs

Misc Letters July 2008 on

Large Prosec Misc Docs

HUD Documents

Transcripts

Miscellaneous Documents

Unpublished Papers

Letters re MHD

Tables

MHD Comments

Figures

ASPI Documents

Web Page PDFs

Sears Documents

Pages Transfer


Case Study II

(June 10, 2013; rev. Jun 7, 2014)

Prefatory note: This subpage is related to Issues 1 and 2 of the Case Study subpage of the Scanlan’s Rule page of jpscanlan.com, which (as clarified by the Case Study Answers  subpage) addresses the problematic nature of standard measures of differences between outcome rates for appraising the likelihood that an employer engaged in discrimination.  Somewhat more elaborate treatments of the point, which also explain a sound method for generally appraising the strength of the forces causing a pair of rates to differ, may be found in Section D of the  Harvard University Measurement Letter (Oct. 9, 2012); Appendix B of the Federal Reserve Board Measurement Letter (Mar. 4, 2013and Section B of the Department of Justice Measurement Letter (Apr. 23, 2012); Section B of the University of Kansas School of Law Faculty Workshop paper “The Mismeasure of Discrimination” (Sept. 20, 2013); and  Section B of Federal Committee on Statistical Methodology 2013 Research Conference paper  “Measuring Health and Healthcare Disparities”(Apr. 2014).  The purpose of the instant subpage is to illustrate implications, with respect to the quantifying of the forces causing a pair of rates to differ, of the fact that sometimes certain parts of the pool of persons potentially subject to a process receive no attention at all from that process (a matter addressed at pages 21-22 of the Kansas School of Law paper.  The issue is somewhat related to the subject of my "Measuring Hiring Discrimination" (Labor Law Journal, July 1993), which involved the interpretation of data in a study of the way “tester” job applicants were treated.

***


Table A below is a slight variation on Table 1 of the Case Study subpage, which presented hypothetical hire rates of an advantaged group (AG) and a disadvantaged group (DG) along with various measures of differences between those rates or between the opposite outcome (rejection) rates.  But, whereas Table 1 of the Case Study subpage presented relative differences between hire rates and relative differences between rejection rates, Table A presents rate ratios for hire and rejection.  This has lately been my preferred method of presenting such information and it was used in the illustrative tables of the letters to Harvard, the Federal Reserve Board, and the Department of Justice.  See Harvard Letter a 6 n6.  The difference between rate ratios and relative differences is only a formal one and neither it, nor the choice of which rate to use in the numerator of a rate ratio, has any bearing on the issues addressed here. 

Table A.  Hypothetical Patterns of Hire Rates of Advantaged and Disadvantage Groups at Four Employers and Measure of Differences between Rates of Hire or Rejection (Based on .5 Standard Deviation Difference Between Means of Underlying Normal Distribution)

 Employer

AG Hire Rate

DG Hire Rate

AG/DG Hire Ratio

DG/AG Rej Ratio

Abs Df

Odds Ratio

A

20.1%

9.0%

2.22 (1)

1.14 (4)

0.11 (4)

2.53 (1)

B

40.1%

22.7%

1.77 (2)

1.29 (3)

0.17 (2)

2.29 (3)

C

59.9%

40.5%

1.48 (3)

1.48 (2)

0.19 (1)

2.19 (4)

D

90.0%

78.2%

1.15 (4)

2.17 (1)

0.12 (3)

2.50 (2)

As explained in various places (perhaps best in the Harvard Letter), while each of the four standard measures of differences between outcome rates would rank these employer differently with respect to the strength of the forces causing AG’s and DG’s rates to differ, so far as can be divined from the information in the table, there is no difference among the employers.  Each reflects a situation where the difference between the means of the underlying hypothesized distributions of factors related to selection or rejection is .5 standard deviations.

But that reasoning is based on an assumption that all applicants are considered by the employer.  There may be many situations where all applicants are not considered.[i]  For example, an employer may receive so many more applications than there are positions to be filled that it will examine only a proportion of those applications.  Similarly, when filling particular vacancies, an employer may examine only applications submitted within a certain period prior to the date of the vacancy. 

Table B is an effort to model such situations based on the assumptions that (a) each employer’s applicants are equally divided between AG and DG; (b) each employer examines only 2.5 times as many applications as there are position to fill; and (c) the process of determining which applications will be considered is neutral with respect to whether an application is submitted by a member of AG or DG.  Thus, the figures in the AG and DG hire rate columns reflect the proportion of each group’s applicants whose applications were examined who were hired – i.e., fractions with the same numerators as in Table 1 but with denominators reduced as a result of the employer’s limiting its review to 2.5 times as many applications as there were positions to fill.   As with Table A, the other figures are calculated on the basis of the data in the hire rate fields. 

The rankings have been eliminated because it has already been demonstrated that they are essentially meaningless.  But the EES (for “estimated effect size”) reflecting the difference between the underlying means estimated on the basis of each pair of selection rates have been added as the final column.

Table B.  Hypothetical Patterns of Hire Rates of Advantaged and Disadvantage Groups at Four Employers and Measure of Differences between Rates of Hire or Rejection, with Estimated Effect Size, Based on Applications Actually Examined by the Employer.

 

Employer

AG Hire Rate (ExApp)

DG Hire Rate(ExApp)

AG/DG HireRatio

DG/AG Rejection Ratio

Abs Dd

Odds Ratio

EES

A

55.30%

24.70%

2.24

1.68

0.31

3.77

.82

B

51.10%

28.90%

1.77

1.45

0.22

2.57

.58

C

59.90%

40.50%

1.48

1.48

0.19

2.19

.50

D

90.00%

78.20%

1.15

2.18

0.12

2.51

.50

Because employers C and D did not have more applications available than the number they would typically consider (given that the overall hire rates were above 50% at both employers and hence that the employers did not have even twice as many applications as they had positions to fill), those employers examined all applications.  Thus, all values for those employer remain as they appeared in Table A. 

In the case of employers A and B, however, the only figure that remains the same is the ratio of AG’s selection rate to DG’s selection rate.  That figure is unchanged because the two groups experience equal proportionate reductions in the denominators of the fractions that constitute their selection rates and thus experience equal proportionate increases in their selection rates.  Ratios of two rates remain constant when the rates change equal proportionate amounts. 

But the rejection rate ratio changes because applications that were not considered at all, and which previously were regarded as rejected applications, are subtracted from the numerator for the rejection rate.  That subtraction does not constitute a proportionate reduction of the numerator but constitutes a larger proportionate reduction in the group with the smaller number of rejections.  I will not belabor the reasons that the absolute differences and odds ratios also change.

It warrants note, however, that because the selection rate ratio does not change, observers who rely on that measure are inclined regard it as unnecessary to consider whether all applications are considered. 

The key figure, however, is the EES.  These figures for employers A and B are higher than before.  And it is these higher figures that better reflect the strength of the forces causing the AG and DG selection rates to differ at these employers.  So under this scenario, the strength of those forces would appear to be greater for employer A than employer B and for both employers A and B than employers C and D. 

Thus, proper analyses of employment discrimination claims must consider only those applications that actually were examined by the employer. 

I am at this point uncertain as to the range of contexts other than analyses of employment discrimination claims where similar issues are implicated.   Such issues would not seem to apply to lending claims since all loan applications are considered by in the decision-making process being examined.

The issue may be implicated in the subject of Table 2 of the Harvard Letter (at 22), which addresses changes in black and white coronary artery bypass graft (CABG) rates during a period of general increases in CABG rates.  I have previously noted that EES may not be a suitable measure of differences in such circumstance because the risk distribution of myocardial infarction (MI) patients may be truncated portions of larger distributions.  See Second Comment on Werner Circulation 2005.  An additional problem would exist if, say, only 10% of acute myocardial infarction patients were suitable candidates for CABG.  In that situation, rather than a reduction of the EES from .58 to .48, as shown in the table, one would observe an increase in the EES from .98 to 1.37.[ii]



[i] That illustration was also based on an assumption that the employer knew the group membership of each applicant.  This illustration is based on the assumption that the employer knew the group membership of each applicant whose application was examined by the employer. 

[ii] There could be any number of complicating factors at work here, including issues pertaining to the comparative suitability of members of different races for CABG in light of differing rates of comorbidity and issues pertaining to the fact that overall differences in treatment may be more a function of overall differences in CABG rates at different hospitals rather than racial differences in CABG rates at the same hospitals.